Vi Digital Library - Text Preview
EU Financial Market Reform: Status and Prospects
Case study by Dullien, Sebastian; Herr, Hansjörg/ HTW, 2010
Download original document (English)
INTERNATIONAL POLICY ANALYSIS
EU Financial Market Reform
Status and Prospects, Spring 2010
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR
May 2010
The financial and economic crisis has made it clear that the financial markets are in
need of far-reaching reform and more effective regulation. Since the most pressing
dangers have been averted and the economy in most industrialised countries is clear
of recession, however, the topic of financial market regulation has largely disap-
peared from the public gaze.
Having said that, a great deal is happening in the background with regard to finan-
cial market regulation, including at the EU level. Against this background, econo-
mists Sebastian Dullien and Hansjörg Herr present the current state of the debate in
some of the most important areas of EU financial market regulation and ongoing
legislative processes and evaluate the most important plans.
The authors come to the conclusion that, although the current deliberations on re-
form are going in the right direction, they are insufficient to ensure the long-term
stability of the EU financial system. For example, the European Commission’s initia-
tives and even more so the ideas of the Council amount to an unacceptable dilution
of the demands of the De Larosière expert group. Dullien and Herr demonstrate
these defects and develop alternative proposals by means of which the European
Parliament could implement substantial EU financial market reforms.
1
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
Content
1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
2 Requirements of Well-Functioning Financial Market Regulation at the EU Level . 3
2.1 Comprehensive, Uniform Oversight of All Products and Institutions . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
2.2 Capital Adequacy Requirements and Rating Agencies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
2.3 New Rules for Derivatives Trading and Securitisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
3 Current Reform Progress at the EU Level . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
3.1 Financial Supervision Package . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7
3.2 Changes in Capital Adequacy Requirements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10
3.3 Stricter Regulation of Rating Agencies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11
3.4 Initiatives on Derivatives Trading and Securitisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12
4 What Next? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13
Literature . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16
3
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
1 Introduction
Since the outbreak of the current financial and economic
crisis in 2007 and its intensification after the collapse of
US investment bank Lehman Brothers in September 2008
there has been no shortage of grandiloquent words as
politicians have sought to describe what is to be done
differently in the financial sector in future. »Making
banking boring« was suddenly the phrase on everyone’s
lips. As late as September 2009, at the G20 summit in
Pittsburgh, the Leaders’ Statement declared: »Today we
agreed: … To make sure our regulatory system for banks
and other financial firms reins in the excesses that led to
the crisis. Where reckless behavior and a lack of respon-
sibility led to crisis, we will not allow a return to banking
as usual«. However, since for the time being critical
threats have been averted and the economies of most
industrialised countries have come out of recession, fi-
nancial market regulation has faded from public view.
This applies in particular to Europe where, traditionally,
legislation at the European level – where decisions on
financial market regulation are made, as a result of the
Single Market – has figured far less prominently in the
predominantly national media than the reporting of
national legislation.
In fact, however, a great deal is happening in the back-
ground with regard to financial market regulation. The
European Commission has already presented a number
of draft directives which are now slowly making their way
through the European decision-making bodies.
The aim of this paper is to present and evaluate the cur-
rent status of the debates and legislative procedures with
regard to some of the most important areas of financial
market regulation. We shall limit ourselves to financial
market supervision and financial market regulation in the
narrow sense. Although the authors are convinced that
macroeconomic imbalances played a significant role in
the origins and outbreak of the global financial and eco-
nomic crisis of 2008–2009, for reasons of space they
must largely be left to one side.1
In what follows, we shall scrutinise three areas of finan-
cial market regulation which have particular significance
for the EU. First, financial market supervision at the EU
level – that is, banking, securities and insurance; second,
1. Those interested might consult Dullien et al. (2009).
the banks’ capital requirements; and third, the regulation
of derivatives markets in the EU, including the rating
agencies.2
2 Requirements of Well-Functioning Financial
Market Regulation at the EU Level
Before attempting to assess current developments in
financial market regulation it is worth taking one more
look at where problems emerged in the latest crisis and
what is required for a better system of financial market
supervision.
2.1 Comprehensive, Uniform Oversight of All Products
and Institutions
A fundamental problem not only with the latest, but also
previous financial and banking crises was often not so
much that the banks were not regulated at home, but
that other financial institutions or other jurisdictions were
less strictly regulated than the native banks and that the
commercial banks took advantage of this by transferring
particularly risky transactions to less regulated parts of
the financial system (regulatory arbitrage). Before the lat-
est crisis, for example, many banks externalised their
transactions involving US subprime securities in the form
of so-called special purpose vehicles, often located in less
regulated financial centres, making it possible, among
other things, to circumvent capital requirements. The risk
remained for the commercial banks through their credit
and ownership links with the so-called »shadow banks«
(Brunnermeier et al. 2009). In the event, this behaviour,
together with the regulatory differences in different parts
of the financial sector, led not only to a more risky, but
also to a more opaque financial system.
The development of the US subprime crisis cannot be
understood without taking a look at the still extremely
fragmented state of financial supervision in the USA. For
example, most subprime mortgages were issued not by
banks, but by mortgage companies which were subject
only to state-level regulation (Gramlich 2007). Many
2. The matters that will not be dealt with explicitly include the control
of hedge funds and other high-risk funds, a European deposit guarantee,
a European bankruptcy law and unregulated – or only lightly – offshore
centres in Europe itself, the purpose of which is to take advantage of
regulatory arbitrage and tax evasion.
4
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
states exercised their regulatory powers so loosely that in
fact there was no regulation at all. The securities of in-
vestment banks were securitised and in any case such
banks were not subject to the same strict rules as normal
commercial banks.
Most authors are therefore in agreement that a central
requirement of a well-functioning and powerful financial
supervision is that it is as complete and comprehensive as
possible. It is crucial that all financial institutions – regard-
less of their legal nature – and all financial products are
included. Regulation should be directed towards what a
product’s function is and what kind of transactions an
institution is involved in, not the legal character of the
product or institution. Only in this way can regulatory ar-
bitrage be effectively prevented (Dullien et al. 2009:
154ff).
At the European level, there are further arguments for
the harmonisation and – at least partial – centralisation
of regulation and oversight in the financial system. On
the one hand, the shifting of transactions to countries
with lower regulatory standards is particularly easy due
to the Single Market. On the other hand, there is a sig-
nificant danger that the consequences of inadequate fi-
nancial market regulation will spill over to the other
countries. First of all, the financial institutions in Europe
are very closely intertwined and second, the current crisis
and the debate on financial assistance for the heavily in-
debted Greece have shown that there is an implicit obli-
gation of liability among the partners for the debts of an
individual country.3 This implies an enormous moral
hazard problem in the absence of a uniform financial
supervision: individual countries always have the incen-
tive to regulate financial institutions more loosely than
other countries do in order to attract them. Potential
costs in the event of a crisis are at least partially exter-
nalised. Even basically uniform rules at the EU level are of
no help against this problem unless there is a uniform
supervision, because national authorities have an incen-
tive to interpret the rules as loosely as possible.
The most sensible option would be a supervisory system
whose structure resembled the European system of cen-
tral banks, with a centralised authority which takes im-
portant decisions and subordinate national authorities
3. The explicit no-bail-out clause has thus in the meantime become an
implicit bail-out guarantee (cf. Dullien / Schwarzer 2009).
which implement these decisions. This would mean su-
pervisory authorities with large staffs on the ground in
the respective countries which, among other things,
would undertake the on-site supervision of financial in-
stitutions – just as, at present, the national central banks
in their day-to-day dealings with the commercial banks
implement the European Central Bank’s (ECB) monetary
policy.
2.2 Capital Adequacy Requirements and
Rating Agencies
Another problem responsible for the current crisis was the
banks’ gluttonous appetite for risk. In all major industri-
alised countries, in recent years, the banks’ capital buffer
has been systematically reduced, causing the debt-equity
ratio – so-called gearing or leverage – to rise rapidly. For
example, equity at institutions such as Deutsche Bank or
the Swiss bank UBS was reduced from almost ten per cent
at the beginning of the 1990s to two to three per cent
before the outbreak of the latest financial market crisis
(Hellwig 2008: 44).
One reason for this development may well have been the
reform of the rules on capital adequacy (the so-called
Basel II standards). The earlier, relatively simple equity
capital guidelines were replaced by new, more complex
guidelines, under which each investment by a bank had
to be backed by equity capital in accordance with its spe-
cific risk. The risk of an investment in each instance was
determined by an internal or external rating.
There were three problems with this. First, using internal
risk models, the dangers arising from certain investments
were likely to be assessed as low as a matter of course.
Although individual risk models had to be approved by
the banking supervision, there was an incentive to adopt
models which evaluated the risks as low and entailed low
capital adequacy. Second, a strong pro-cyclical element
was introduced into the banks’ lending. Ratings tend to
improve systematically in an upswing and to be down-
graded in a downturn. In connection with Basel II, the
problem arose that, in good times, the banks did not
have to hold so much capital and thus could expand their
credit portfolio. This is likely to have further fuelled the
boom, for example, in mortgage allocation. In the down-
turn, in contrast, more equity capital was abruptly re-
quired, so that the banks, in the very period in which the
5
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
economy needed more expansive lending, were forced to
curtail it. Third, the close links between financial institu-
tions and rating agencies became problematic: because,
in particular, the evaluation of structured financial prod-
ucts was very profitable for the rating agencies and, at
the same time, such evaluations were commissioned and
paid for by the issuing financial institutions, there was an
incentive to provide even dubious products with good
ratings. Furthermore, for smaller financial institutions,
which do not use their own risk models, rating agencies
took over risk evaluation.
Commercial banks traditionally pursued a business model
which concentrated, first and foremost, on lending to
non-financial institutions, that is, to companies, private
households and public authorities. In addition, banks
traded on capital markets, currency markets and other
speculative markets on behalf of others. In particular,
banks operating internationally in recent years have dra-
matically increased the volume of proprietary trading.
This means that they carried out speculative bond, for-
eign currency, precious metals and, not least, derivatives
transactions on their own account.
These risky transactions on the part of the commercial
banks should be strictly limited in order to prevent them
from using their privileged access to central banks (to re-
finance their lending) to engage in highly speculative ac-
tivities. One option would be to impose particularly high
capital requirements – up to 100 per cent – on proprie-
tary trading. Alternatively, a far-reaching ban on specula-
tive transactions in the proprietary trading of commercial
banks should be contemplated. US President Barack
Obama, based on the recommendations of former Chair-
man of the Federal Reserve Paul Volcker, has proposed
reforms along these lines.4 Both options would also lead
to a limitation or even reduction of the size of financial
institutions, which in any case is desirable on regulatory
grounds. To be sure, in both instances it must be ensured
that commercial bank loans to other highly speculative
actors in the financial sector – hedge funds, private equity
funds and so on – are limited. Likewise, in this case par-
ticularly high capital requirements and an outright ban
are equally worthy of consideration.
The commercial banks not only engaged in risky trans-
actions in proprietary trading, but also financed other fi-
4. Cf. Financial Times Deutschland, 21 January 2010.
nancial institutions, such as investment banks, hedge
funds and private equity funds, whose business models
are, as a rule, highly risk oriented and speculative. As a
result, a direct channel emerged between the creation of
money by central banks, the commercial banks’ credit
expansion and the credit financed speculation of risk-
taking financial market actors. The central banks had no
instrument at their disposal to promote credit expansion
in productive branches or to impede the financing of
speculative activities, which led to asset market bubbles.
For risk capital – for example, in the form of venture
capital – more than enough funds are still available, be-
cause non-commercial banks can attract investments, for
example, from risk-seeking private households.
The revision of equity capital rules is therefore key to
effective reform of financial market regulations. The fol-
lowing points are of particular importance in this regard:
1. Capital requirements should, by and large, be higher
than they are now.
2. Banks should be compelled to back transactions
externalised in special purpose vehicles or similar institu-
tions with equity capital.
3. The hitherto pro-cyclical effects of equity capital rules
should be eliminated, for example, by introducing obliga-
tions on banks, in good times, to build up capital reserves
or by means of capital requirements which vary counter-
cyclically over the economic cycle.
4. The rating agencies’ role in the process should be
reduced; furthermore, rating agencies’ payment model
should be changed so that they no longer have an incen-
tive to evaluate securities in the interests of their issuers.
The establishment of a European rating agency could
break the monopoly of the private rating agencies, which
have failed.
5. Commercial banks’ proprietary trading must be sub-
ject to very high capital requirements. The same applies
to commercial banks’ lending to non-banks in the finan-
cial sector. Alternatively, proprietary trading could be
banned and strict limits considered on commercial banks’
loans to non-bank financial institutions.
6
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
2.3 New Rules for Derivatives Trading and
Securitisation
Another problem which has attracted renewed attention
in the current crisis is the growing significance of unregu-
lated bilateral trading – over the counter or OTC – of fi-
nancial derivatives. A particular focus is the market for
credit default swaps (CDS) which, according to current
estimates, is now worth more than 60 trillion US dollars.
Many have predicted that problems on the CDS market
could usher in a new round of bank failures.5 This funda-
mental problem of the CDS market also applies to many
other derivatives and financial innovations.
One of the main difficulties of the derivatives market is
that, because of its bilateral nature, it is unclear which
market participants hold what positions and whether
there is a concentration of risk or not. In the event of
more dramatic price movements or the insolvency of a
firm the purchaser of a derivative – for example, a CDS –
can find itself in financial difficulties. Furthermore, if an
OTC counterparty goes bankrupt, the other also comes
under threat. In the past, market participants just blindly
assumed that OTC counterparties could always step into
the breach. In this way, business strategies were classed,
from a microeconomic perspective, as safeguarded, al-
though from a macroeconomic perspective it ought to
have been clear that this was not the case. As a result,
financial institutions signalled solvency and liquidity posi-
tions from the microeconomic level which rapidly proved
to be illusory in the crisis.
Precisely these dangers manifested themselves in the
course of the nationalisation of US insurance group AIG
and the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers. AIG had enor-
mous sums outstanding in CDSs, so that the US govern-
ment feared a domino effect of bank failures if the com-
pany went bankrupt. There was a similar fear in the case
of the investment bank Lehman Brothers, which ulti-
mately led to the state more or less doing whatever it
took to rescue the situation after its collapse. The fact
was, however, that the supervisory authorities simply
could not foresee the consequences of insolvencies.
One solution to the problem of risky OTC derivatives
markets would be to transfer all such transactions to cen-
tral clearing houses on a compulsory basis. A central
5. See, for example, Münchau (2009).
clearing house would have a number of advantages.
First, regulators would be provided with summary infor-
mation on current risks, as all transactions would go
through it. Regulators could see at a glance who had
taken what positions and counterpositions, so that the
net risk of a bank failure could be more easily assessed.
Second, a central clearing house would provide some
sort of protection in the selection of counterparties in de-
rivatives trading: depending on the development of lia-
bilities from derivatives contracts counterparties would
have to deposit a certain proportion of these liabilities at
the clearing house in the form of bank deposits or highly
liquid government bonds. Although it would not be ab-
solutely guaranteed that the counterparties could even-
tually fulfil their commitments, the accumulation of ex-
tremely risky positions almost without the use of own
funds would be prevented. Third, the obligation to de-
posit liquid securities automatically limits the amount of
derivatives that individual financial institutions can issue.
In this way, in turn, the risk and volume of the derivatives
market, if desired, can be reduced relatively simply by in-
creasing the deposit obligation and ensuring that deriva-
tives trades involve a higher proportion of investors’ own
funds. A higher deposit obligation functions like a fee
which makes hedging transactions moderately more ex-
pensive and counteracts an excessively high inclination
towards risk on the markets.
With the securitisation of credit instruments the original
lender sells his claims arising from lending to a third party.
A large number of loans can, as frequently happened be-
fore the subprime crisis, be pooled and divided into
tranches, allowing the process to be repeated a number
of times. The distance between the original lender and
the final holder of the loan, who bears the default risk,
thereby becomes greater. The risk of moral hazard also
emerges because the original lender, in granting credit,
no longer applies strict standards, since he can sell the
risks and de facto operates as a credit broker. Rating
agencies, as the subprime crisis has shown, were not in a
position to evaluate sometimes very complex securitisa-
tions adequately. In order to solve this problem we pro-
pose that the original lender should be obliged to hold
an appropriate portion of the granted credit until the
term of the loan is reached.6 It must be taken into ac-
count that the original lender holds a large portion of the
6. The SPD party executive’s project group »More Transparency and
Stability on the Financial Markets« in October 2008 called for the reten-
tion of 20 per cent. This seems appropriate to us.
7
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
»first loss« part, that is, the tranche which suffers first in
the event of default.
The question arises, in the face of the seemingly relent-
less emergence of financial innovations – which overall
make financial markets increasingly opaque, even for ex-
perts and supervisory authorities – of how to deal with
new financial products. A large number of these prod-
ucts are not financial innovations at all, but rather the
result of regulatory arbitrage. In Dullien et al. (2009), the
introduction of a financial »MOT« (in German: TÜV or
Technischer Überwachungs-Verein [Technical Inspection
Association]) is proposed as a solution. In contrast to
what is usually put forward when this matter is raised in
the public debate, it would not, in the first instance, be
the task of a financial MOT to bar access to certain risky
forms of investment to small investors. The point would
rather be to subject all products – that is, also those in
use only in inter-bank trading – to strict examination be-
fore they are introduced on the market.
The approach taken to the licensing of drugs should
serve as the model here: a financial institution which
wants to introduce a new product or a new type of con-
tract must first prove that the individual or national eco-
nomic use of the new product is proportionate to the risk
and to any increase in market opacity on account of the
product. Products which represent no discernible im-
provement over existing contracts should be rejected in
this process, as should innovations with excessive risk.
Good innovations, in contrast, may continue to be devel-
oped and find their way into the market.
3 Current Reform Progress at the EU Level
Many of the elements proposed above are reflected in
the proposals being discussed at the EU level. Of central
importance for the EU debate is the report by the so-
called De Larosière Group, which was ordered by the
European Commission and presented in February 2009,
which more or less serves as the basis for the proposals
for a Directive which the Commission got under way in
the course of 2009.
3.1 Financial Supervision Package
A key element of the Commission proposals is the cre-
ation of a European System for Financial Supervision
(ESFS). Basically, the idea of a unified supervisory struc-
ture goes back to the outline presented by the De
Larosière Group (De Larosière Report 2009: p. 48ff), the
proposed structure of which was adopted virtually unal-
tered in the draft directive presented by the European
Commission in September 2009 (European Commission
2009).
This system is intended to form a network of European
financial supervisory authorities (see Figure 1). The three
previously existing so-called »Level 3 committees« for the
regulation of banks, insurance companies and securities
supervision – the Committee of European Banking Super-
visors (CEBS), the Committee of European Insurance and
Occupational Pensions (CEIOPS) and the Committee of
European Securities Regulators (CESR) – are to be up-
graded to authorities with offices in Frankfurt, Paris and
London. At the same time, national supervisory authori-
ties would continue to be concerned mainly with the su-
pervision of financial institutions and markets, while the
newly established European Supervisory Authorities (ESA)
are to adopt a coordination function and, among other
things, »coordinate the application of common high level
supervisory standards«, as well as directly monitoring in-
dividual cross-border institutions.
A European Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) is to be set up
alongside these Supervisory Authorities, to assess macro-
economic risks and make recommendations when things
take a wrong turn. The plan is that the ESRB’s Taxation
Committee should have 33 voting members, namely the
27 national central bank heads, the ECB President and
vice-president, a representative of the European Commis-
sion and the heads of the three ESAs. The main task of
this committee would be to issue warnings and recom-
mendations. The ESRB’s secretariat is to be located at the
ECB in Frankfurt.
Apart from the basic structure, the powers envisaged for
the Authorities in the legislative process represent a
marked dilution in comparison to the De Larosière pro-
posal. In the De Larosière Report, ESA experts were
granted relatively substantial »break-through rights« in
the form of mandatory instructions to national supervi-
sory authorities. For example, it had been recommended
8
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
that the new authorities could challenge »the perfor-
mance by any national supervisor of its supervisory re-
sponsibilities … and to issue rulings aimed at ensuring
that national supervisors correct the weaknesses that
have been identified. In the event of the national supervi-
sor failing to respond to this ruling, a series of graduated
sanctions could be applied …« (De Larosière Report
2009: 60f).
In the draft presented by the European Commission
(2009a; 2009b; 2009c) in September this idea no longer
had the clarity of the first draft. It is true that the Euro-
pean Commission was given the right, when weaknesses
in the implementation of EU financial market regulations
by national financial supervisions came to the notice of
the new EU authorities, to force them to change their
policies. Furthermore, the direct practical powers of the
new European authorities in relation to financial institu-
tions such as rating agencies, central counterparties, in-
cluding clearing houses, and similar European institutions
were limited. This means that break-through rights with
regard to »normal« financial institutions which operate
predominantly at the cross-border level were dropped.
In comparison to the Commission’s draft, the draft dis-
cussed in the Council of Ministers in December 2009
(Council of the European Union 2009) represented even
thinner gruel. For example, the direct »breakthrough
rights« of the planned European authorities with regard
to financial institutions were further restricted and explic-
itly limited to rating agencies. What is more important,
however, is that in this draft the European Commission’s
Figure 1 A new European framework for safeguarding financial market stability
M
ac
ro
-p
ru
de
nt
ia
l s
up
er
vi
si
on »European Systemic Risk Council« (ESRC)
[Chaired by President ECB] Main tasks of the European Systemic Risk Council:
decide on macro-prudential policy, provide early risk
warning to EU supervisors, compare observations on
macro-economic and prudential developments and
give direction on these issues.Members of ECB/ESCB
General Council
(with alternates where
necessary)
+
Chairs of
EBA, EIA&ESA
+
European
Commission
Information on
micro-prudential
developments
Early risk warning
M
ic
ro
-p
ru
de
nt
ia
l s
up
er
vi
si
on
»European System of Financial Supervision« (ESFS)
Main tasks of the Authorities: in addition to the
competences of the existing level 3 committees, the
Authorities would have the following key-competenc-
es: (i) legally binding mediation between national su-
pervisors, (ii) adoption of binding supervisory standards,
(iii) adoption of binding technical decisions applicable
to individual institutions, (iv) oversight and coordination
of colleges of supervisors, (v) licensing and supervi-
sion of specific EU-wide institutions (e.g., Credit Rating
Agencies and posttrading infrastructures), (vi) binding
cooperation with the ESRC to ensure adequate macro-
prudential supervision, and (vii) strong coordinating role
in crisis situations.
Main tasks of national supervisors: continue to be
fully responsible for day-to-day supervision of firms.
»European Banking
Authority« (EBA)
»European Insurance
Authority« (EIA)
»European Securities
Authority« (ESA)
National Banking
Supervisors
National Insurance
Supervisors
National Securities
Supervisors
Source: De Larosière Report (2009), p. 65.
9
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
authority to issue instructions to national supervisory au-
thorities is deleted and downgraded to a mere recom-
mendation. Furthermore, the European authorities’ deci-
sion-making competence in an emergency is withdrawn.
Finally, the draft envisages the possibility of member
states exercising a veto against decisions of the European
financial market supervision if they threaten their bud-
getary sovereignty. A critical feature of this provision is
that, according to the Council draft, no justification is re-
quired with regard to why an individual member state
considers its budgetary sovereignty to have been jeop-
ardised and that such a veto automatically has a suspen-
sive effect on the European authority’s decision.
The package is currently being debated in the European
Parliament and its first reading is due in May or June 2010.
The question is, whether the Parliament will go along
with the Council’s desired changes or risk a conciliation
procedure. The problem with such a conciliation proce-
dure may be that the supervision directives are unlikely to
be adopted in 2010.
The current state of reform with regard to financial mar-
ket supervision represents an improvement in relation to
the status quo, but it has grave defects which may hinder
the emergence of a truly powerful and efficient EU finan-
cial market supervision through the planned directive.7
It is generally to be welcomed that further competences
are being transferred to the financial supervision at the
European level. This is a step which can prevent geo-
graphical regulatory arbitrage. Also generally positive is
the fact that a special committee will be devoted at the
European level to the topic of systemic risk and macro-
economic risks.
It is difficult to understand the planned structure of the
supervisory authority, however. The division into three
authorities, separated both geographically and in terms
of subject-matter, is problematic. It is becoming increas-
ingly difficult to assign modern financial institutions to a
certain segment of the financial sector. The division of
supervisory competence to three authorities brings with
it the danger of divergent application of regulations and
of transitions which lead to regulatory gaps. The recent
crisis furnishes a vivid illustration of this: the US insurance
7. This section is based on Sebastian Dullien’s testimony before the Eu-
ropean Parliament’s ECON Committee in January 2010 (Dullien 2010).
group AIG was not forced onto the ropes on account of
its insurance business, but because it gambled in the
credit derivatives market, more precisely with credit de-
fault swaps (CDS). The US government took the view
that it had no choice but to stage a rescue because AIG
had engaged in such transactions with a multitude of
banks and its bankruptcy would also have dragged these
institutions under. The danger is that a fragmented su-
pervision, like the one planned by the EU, would fail to
see such connections.
The same applies to the geographical division of supervi-
sory competence and the location of the authorities in
three different cities and countries. Recognising the risks
emerging at the interfaces between individual financial
institutions requires the active exchange of views by su-
pervisory personnel at all levels. The danger of geograph-
ical separation is that, although there will be regular
meetings at the top level, those working at the coalface
will be too isolated from one another to identify every
threat in time.
Turning to the ESRB, its close linkage to the European
Central Bank is a matter of concern. Although central
banks have privileged access to information on financial
stability, and the ECB has regularly published its Financial
Stability Review since 2004, central banks tend to think
and act by strict consensus. Most European central bank-
ers are trained on the basis of similar models and modes
of thinking, while many years of cooperation lead to fur-
ther convergence of worldviews. As the US subprime cri-
sis illustrated, it is often outsiders who identify risks. For
example, the US Federal Reserve long ignored the risks
attendant on the house price bubble, while economists
such as Raghuram Rajan and Robert Shiller sounded the
alarm. Experience of earlier financial crises shows that
they generally do not arise where financial crises arose
before, and that the dominant economic interpretation
often underestimates developing threats. It would there-
fore be important to integrate maverick opinions in the
evaluation of macroeconomic and systemic risks. This is
ruled out by the overwhelming majority of 29 out of 33
votes for central bankers in the ESRB.
A further problem is the question of how central bankers
in the committee react when ECB policy becomes a sys-
temic risk. The question is whether, for example, the cen-
tral bankers in the ESRB would agree to issue a warning
about an over-hasty series of interest rate hikes by the
10
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
ECB, if they jeopardised macroeconomic stability in Eu-
rope.
Finally, it has to be said that, so far, the ECB has not ex-
actly covered itself with glory in its crisis assessments. For
example, in July 2008 – that is, almost one year after the
first appearance of turbulence on the money markets
(and when Europe’s economy, as we now know, was al-
ready in recession) – the ECB raised interest rates once
more. This, albeit small, interest rate increase is likely to
have further aggravated the situation in the European
banking sector. The ECB’s decision can be explained only
by the fact that it failed to perceive the seriousness of the
situation at that time. There is no reason to believe that
the ECB will do better in the future than it has so far.
To sum up, a better solution to the problems of financial
sector supervision would be to create a single supervisory
authority for the whole financial sector in one city (and
best of all, in one building), which is responsible for the
banks, insurance companies and the securities markets
alike.
3.2 Changes in Capital Adequacy Requirements
The De Larosière Report regards the reduction of the eq-
uity capital of financial institutions as one of the reasons
for the subprime crisis, and proposes a »fundamental re-
view« of the Basel II framework (De Larosière Report
2009: 22). In detail, it is proposed to gradually increase
the minimum capital requirements, to reduce the procy-
clical effect of Basel II, to introduce stricter rules for off-
balance sheet positions, to tighten up liquidity manage-
ment and to reinforce the provisions on internal control
and risk management of banks. The Basel Committee of
Banking Supervisors is called on to make the appropriate
changes speedily. The Report also proposes the establish-
ment of a common definition of regulatory capital, which
should be confirmed by the Basel Committee. With refer-
ence to the mechanical application of banks’ internal risk
models there is also an explicit demand for management
personnel and board members to make greater use of
their own judgement and to possess high personal integ-
rity and technical knowledge (De Larosière Report 2009:
22).
Concerning the shadow banking system, the Report calls
for all firms of potential significance for the financial sys-
tem to be subject to appropriate regulation. Particularly
in the case of systemically important hedge funds a
worldwide obligation to register and to provide informa-
tion on strategies, methods and leverage, also in global
transactions, is called for. For banks which conduct pro-
prietary trading, an appropriate capital requirement
should be set. This also applies to banks which are own-
ers or operators of hedge funds (De Larosière Report
2009: 28f).
Although the proposals of the De Larosière Report do not
include quantitative stipulations, their overall thrust is
relatively far-reaching. The sole relevant difference with
regard to our approach concerns whether proprietary
trading should be permitted for commercial banks and
how commercial bank lending to hedge funds and other
non-bank financial intermediaries should be dealt with.
On this the Group proposes that, in the case of banks
which conduct proprietary trading and are owners or op-
erators of hedge funds, an appropriate capital require-
ment should be enforced. In our view, such a proposal is
certainly a step in the right direction. However, clear pro-
posals are lacking on how commercial banks’ lending
relationships to the shadow banking system can be pre-
vented or at least so strictly limited that the spread of
problems from the shadow banking system to the normal
banking system can be avoided.
On 6 May 2009, the European Parliament approved a
tightening up of banks’ capitalisation, which is supposed
to be adopted in the member states by 31 October 2010
and come into force by the end of the year (European
Parliament 2009; Stichele 2009). More specifically, it was
laid down that banks may allocate no more than 25 per
cent of their capital to one client or group of clients.8 It
was also agreed that, in the case of securitisations, a re-
tention of at least 5 per cent should apply. Criteria were
also more clearly defined for the »duty of care« in the
valuation of securitisations.
In July 2009, the European Commission presented pro-
posals for the further tightening up of financial institu-
tions’ capital holdings (Europa Press Releases 2009a). A
consultation process then commenced on the proposals,
which was concluded in September 2009. The key ele-
ments of the Commission proposals are as follows:
8. In future, balance sheet capitalisation can only include up to a max-
imum of 35 per cent of capital subject to withdrawal.
11
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
1. In the case of re-securitisations, banks should be sub-
ject to higher capital requirements.
2. The new provisions are to tighten up disclosure re-
quirements with regard to securitisation risks. Accord-
ingly, banks must clearly identify and publish risks related
to securitisations.
3. Capital requirements for the trading book are to be
modified in such a way that the banks take full account
of potential losses which could occur as a result of un-
favourable market developments in stress situations,
such as those encountered in 2008 and 2009. The trad-
ing book includes all financial instruments held by a bank
in order to resell them in the short term or in order to
cover other instruments in the trading book, that is, es-
sentially the bank’s proprietary trading.
4. Banks’ remuneration policy and practice are to be de-
signed in such a way that an excessive willingness to take
risks is neither encouraged nor rewarded. Banking super-
visors can sanction banks which do not comply with the
new provisions.
The European Commission’s proposals are disappointing
with regard to bank capitalisation. Although higher cap-
italisation is implicitly proposed in the case of banks’ pro-
prietary trading, including re-securitisations, it is not suf-
ficient. It would be much better to tightly restrict banks’
proprietary trading. The banks’ banking book, which
should include longer-term planned investments, such as
receivables from loans or securities and thus the banks’
core business, is not even discussed with regard to capital
adequacy. No general increase in bank capitalisation is
provided for, nor the introduction of countercyclical ele-
ments with regard to capitalisation, in particular includ-
ing banks’ banking book. Commercial relationships with
non-bank financial intermediaries, such as hedge funds
and commercial banks, are not addressed and play no
role with regard to capital adequacy obligations. The
European Commission’s proposals with regard to capi-
talisation fall far short of the ideas contained in the De
Larosière Report. As things stand at the moment, no far-
reaching reform measures are to be expected from the
European Commission with regard to bank capitalisation.
Having said that, it can be seen that the subprime crisis
and its consequences have kick-started a Basel III. The
defects of Basel II are so deep that even its developers are
discussing reform. The Basel Committee will give its opin-
ion on a Basel III in April 2010. The European Commission
will then make its own comments.
There can be no objection to disclosure obligations with
regard to securitisation risks and the supervision of banks’
remuneration policy and practice, but these are »soft«
areas of regulation which, although important, are not
sufficient.
3.3 Stricter Regulation of Rating Agencies
With regard to rating agencies, the De Larosière Report
demands that their licensing and supervision be trans-
ferred to a reinforced European supervisory institution,
the Committee of European Securities Regulators (CESR).
Rating agencies’ business models and financing, as well
as their combination of valuation and consultation ac-
tivities are to be subjected to fundamental examination.
Specific provisions must be introduced for the rating of
structured products. Finally, the use of ratings in financial
provisions should be severely restricted (De Larosière Re-
port 2009: 23).
With regard to the regulation of rating agencies, reform
measures were instigated at the EU level. In November
2009, a Regulation on the subject was issued (Official
Journal of the European Union 2009; European Parlia-
ment 2009a). The key points of the Regulation are that
rating agencies headquartered in the Community will
have to register with the European supervisory authority,
the CESR. The rating agencies are regulated by the com-
petent authority of the respective member state of origin,
in cooperation with other member states. It is under con-
sideration to include the CESR in this system. Further-
more, under the new Regulation, rating agencies are for-
bidden to issue ratings for a given company or involved
third parties if they are also providing it with consulting
services. The rating of financial instruments may only
take place on the basis of well-founded information.
There must be annual transparency reports on the rating
agencies’ fundamental assumptions, models and meth-
ods. Structured products must be specifically designated
by rating agencies. With regard to the internal control of
rating agencies, there must be at least two independent
members on the administrative or supervisory board of
agencies, who are remunerated independently, serve a
one-off maximum term of five years and may be dis-
missed only on the grounds of professional impropriety.
12
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
At least one member must be an expert on securitisation
and structured financial instruments.
The EU Regulation falls short of the De Larosière Report
on one important point. In the latter, the supervision of
rating agencies by a reinforced European supervisory in-
stitution was envisaged. In the Regulation, supervision
remains a matter of national regulation. The financing of
rating agencies by the company issuing the securities to
be rated was not changed, either. As a result, a key ele-
ment of the dependency of rating agencies remains,
which is a clear instance of moral hazard, affecting their
rating activities.
3.4 Initiatives on Derivatives Trading and Securitisation
The De Larosière Report proposes with regard to deriva-
tives markets that OTC derivatives be simplified and stan-
dardised (De Larosière Report 2009: 29). It remains an
open question, however, how this is to be done. For
CDSs, which are regarded as particularly dangerous, the
Report proposes a well-capitalised central clearing house
for the whole EU. The clearing house should be super-
vised by the European supervisory authorities, including
the ECB. With regard to securitisation, it is proposed that
all issuers of securitised products must retain a significant
portion of the underlying risk, which is not insured by
hedging, for the entire lifetime of the instrument (De
Larosière Report 2009: 29). As in the case of capital ad-
equacy, the proposals of the De Larosière Report are fairly
far-reaching. It would have been more consistent, how-
ever, if the Report had called for a state-supervised clear-
ing house for all derivatives transactions. One defect of
the Report is that it did not propose the introduction of
a financial MOT.
After the first draft in July 2009 and consultations
(Stichele 2009), in October 2009 the European Commis-
sion presented proposals on the regulation of derivatives
markets based on the De Larosière Report and consulta-
tions with interest groups (Europa Press Releases 2009).
The proposals are in line with the G20 declaration in Pitts-
burgh. In order to rule out regulatory arbitrage and to
ensure globally coherent policy approaches the Commis-
sion is willing to cooperate with authorities from all over
the world, before finalising its legislative proposals. Draft
bills should be presented in the course of 2010. The key
points of the Commission proposals are as follows:
1. Risk of default is to be prevented. For that purpose,
legal provisions should be put forward to establish com-
mon safety, regulatory and operating standards for cen-
tral clearing houses (central counterparties). The collater-
alisation of OTC transactions is to be improved. Capital
requirements with regard to OTC transactions are to be
significantly increased in comparison to transactions car-
ried out through a central clearing house. For stan-
dardised contracts, clearing through a central counter-
party is to be made mandatory.
2. Operational risk is to be reduced. For that purpose,
the standardisation of contract conditions and contract
management is to be actively pursued.
3. Transparency is to be increased. Market participants
are to be obliged to enter positions and transactions
which are not carried out through central clearing houses
in transaction registers, which are to be regulated and
supervised. Transparency will also be enhanced by the
fact that standardised derivatives transactions may only
be carried out via organised trading centres. All deriva-
tives markets are to be covered, including commodity
derivatives.
4. Market integrity and supervision are to be improved.
Existing regulations against market manipulation and so
on are to be extended to derivatives. Regulatory authori-
ties are to be given the possibility to set position limits.
The intentions of the Commission, which were character-
ised by Charlie McCreevy as »a paradigm shift away from
the traditional view that derivatives are financial instru-
ments for professional use and thus require only light-
handed regulation« (Europa Press Releases 2009), are
largely identical to the proposals of the De Larosière Re-
port.
However, it would have been better if the Commission
had proposed that all derivatives transactions be carried
out through organised clearing houses. The idea of a fi-
nancial MOT was also left out, as it was from the De
Larosière Report. However, only a financial MOT can end
the pursuit of a succession of new structured products
which in many areas are intransparent and of no benefit
for economic development.
13
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
4 What Next?
Taking the De Larosière Group’s Report as a starting
point, it is fair to say that, while the proposals with regard
to a European financial market supervision, the capitali-
sation of banks and the regulation of derivatives markets
are a step in the right direction, they fall far short of en-
suring the long-lasting stability of the financial system. In
particular, the segmentation of financial market super-
vision in the EU and the design of the committee that is
to supervise macroeconomic financial market stability are
unsatisfactory. As far as the banks are concerned, one
would have wished for tighter restrictions on banks’ pro-
prietary trading, the business relations of commercial
banks with the shadow banking system and a commit-
ment to a financial MOT.
Previous Regulations at the EU level and the European
Commission initiatives mentioned in this article represent
a marked and unacceptable dilution of the demands of
the De Larosière Report. Furthermore, the Council’s
stance again falls short of the Commission’s proposals.
Proposals which were a lot closer to those of the De
Larosière Report would have been much better, notwith-
standing the fact that the latter is hardly a radical docu-
ment itself (see overview in Table 1).
What next? First, it should be emphasised that even the
Commission proposals watered down by the Council rep-
resent an improvement of the status quo. There is not a
single area in which existing provisions are relaxed. The
planned new authorities have the sole purpose of pre-
venting the inadequate application of European regula-
tions at the national level. Further, stricter rules at the
national level, such as the »dynamic provisioning« – a
countercyclical loan provisioning measure – stipulated for
commercial banks in Spain before the crisis, remain pos-
sible. It is also conceivable in principle that the single-
currency states agree among themselves on separate,
stricter rules for their financial institutions.
However, strongly integrated financial systems are only
ever as stable as their weakest systemically important
element. Different degrees of regulatory stringency
within the single European market in effect encourage
regulatory arbitrage. Sustainable stabilisation of the
European financial system by means of nation-states
going it alone simply will not work.
The question for the European Parliament is whether it
accepts the proposals now on the table or insists on
stricter rules and a more coherent supervisory structure.
When this translation of this study was being completed
(beginning of May), it became apparent that the Parlia-
ment’s ECON Committee would suggest a large number
of changes to the present draft legislation. Since the re-
sults of the voting in the Committee are not yet available
and the concluding readings and votes have not yet hap-
pened in Parliament, there is no analysis in this study of
the Parliament’s proposals. It is clear, however, that a
large number of proposed changes, or changes that are
particularly far-reaching, could delay the whole legisla-
tion on a European supervisory architecture and stricter
regulations because, besides a second reading, a concili-
ation procedure could also be necessary. This would
make it difficult to get the regulations finally adopted by
the end of 2010. The danger here is that such a delay
might be a tough sell to the voters. Weighing up the pros
and cons of the various strategies, the best option would
probably be for the Parliament to take a tough line. First
of all, there is no need for undue haste, at present. A new
financial crisis is unlikely to unfold over the months or
year which would be needed to establish the new super-
visory structure. Second, there is the danger that the
adoption of new laws would result in the creation of per-
manent unsatisfactory structures which, not least on ac-
count of the particular interests of the new supervisory
personnel, will be almost impossible to change at a later
date. It is therefore important to design these structures
and regulations rationally from the outset and simply to
accept a certain delay in their implementation.
14
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
Table 1: Overview of the state of financial market reform in the EU
Regulatory area De Larosière Group proposal State of the debate with regard
to EU legislation*
Comment / assessment
Microprudential
Supervision
– Three EU supervisory authori-
ties: for banks, insurance
companies and securities
– Network of EU and national
authorities
– »Breakthrough rights« at the
EU level with regard to na-
tional authorities
– Supervision of pan-European
financial institutions by EU
authorities
Commission proposal:
Like the De Larosière-Group, but:
– limited breakthrough rights for
the EU authorities
– direct supervision only of clear-
ing houses, rating agencies, etc.
Council proposal:
Like the Commission, but:
– no authority to issue directives
for the European Commission in
relation to national authorities
– direct supervision only of Euro-
pean rating agencies
– implicit veto of member states
with regard to decisions of the
EU authorities
– An integrated supervisory
authority for all parts of the
financial sector would be
preferable
– Dilution of breakthrough
rights by the Commission and
Council proposals is unac-
ceptable
Macroprudential
Supervision
– Introduction of a European
Systemic Risk Board (ESRB) to
monitor macroeconomic sta-
bility
– Strong weighting of central
banks in the ESRB
Like the De Larosière Group – Weighting of central bankers
in the ESRB should be ur-
gently reduced
– Outsiders (academics etc.)
should be included in the
process
Capital require-
ments
– Increase in capital require-
ments
– More equity capital for securi-
tisations
– More equity capital for off-
balance sheet obligations
– Uniform definition of equity
capital
– More equity capital for pro-
prietary trading
– Prevention of procyclical ef-
fects of equity capital provi-
sions
– Equity capital requirements for
re-securitisations are increased
– Equity capital requirements for
proprietary trading increased
Improvements necessary:
– Capital requirements for pro-
prietary trading insufficient
– No adequate capital require-
ments for loans to the
shadow banking system
– So far, no solution for the
problem of procyclicality
Derivatives
trading
– OTC derivatives are to be sim-
plified and standardised
– There is to be a well-capital-
ised central clearing house
for CDSs
– Promotion of the standardisa-
tion of contract conditions and
contract management
– Promotion of a central clearing
house for standardised con-
tracts
– Transaction register for OTC
transactions
Improvements necessary:
– Central clearing house should
be made binding
– Derivatives should be stan-
dardised via a financial MOT
15
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
Regulatory area De Larosière Group proposal State of the debate with regard
to EU legislation*
Comment / assessment
Rating agencies – Supervision at the EU level
– Supervision of business and
financing models
– Prohibition of simultaneous
consultation and ratings for
the same client
– Binding provisions for the rat-
ing of structured products
– Restriction of the use of rat-
ings in financial provisions
– New transparency provisions
– Prohibition of simultaneous con-
sultation and ratings for the
same client
– Registration obligation with re-
gard to EU supervisory authori-
ties
Improvements necessary:
Adoption of the proposals of the
De Larosière Group
Financial MOT Not envisaged Like the De Larosière Group Introduction urgently recom-
mended; for guidance, refer to
the procedure for drug approval
* Unless noted otherwise, Commission proposal.
16
SEBASTIAN DULLIEN AND HANSJÖRG HERR | EU FINANCIAL MARKET REFORM
Literature
Official Gazette of the European Union (2009): Regulation (EC) No. 1060/2009 of the European Parliament and of the
Council of 16 September 2009 on credit rating agencies.
Brunnermeier, M., A. Crocket, C. Goodhart, A.D. Persaud and H. Shin (2009): The Fundamental Principles of Financial
Regulation. Geneva Reports on the World Economy 11: Geneva.
De Larosière Report (2009): Brussels.
Dullien, S. (2010): Testimony on the planned reform of macroprudential supervision in Europe in front of the ECON Com-
mittee of the European Parliament, 25 January 2010: Brussels. Available at: http://www.euro-area.org/blog/?p=252.
Dullien, S., H. Herr and C. Kellermann (2009): Der gute Kapitalismus. Bielefeld: Transcript Verlag.
Dullien, S. and D. Schwarzer (2009): Gerettet wird immer. Financial Times Deutschland, 13 February 2009, p. 26.
European Commission (2009a): Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing a
European Banking Authority. COM (2009) 499.
European Commission (2009b), Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing a
European Insurance and Occupational Pensions Authority. COM (2009) 502.
European Commission (2009c): Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council establishing a
European Securities and Markets Authority. COM (2009) 503.
Europa Press Releases (2009): Financial services: Commission sets out future actions to strengthen the safety of derivatives
markets. Reference: IP/09/1546, 20 October 2009.
Europa Press Releases (2009a): Commission proposes further revision of banking regulation to strengthen rules on bank
capital and on remuneration in the banking sector. Reference: IP/09/1120, 13 July 2009.
European Parliament (2009): New rules to avoid future financial crisis – Capital Requirements Directives. Press release of
6 May 2009.
Gramlich, E.M. (2007): Subprime Mortgages: America’s Latest Boom and Bust. Urban Institute Press.
Helwig, M. (2008): Systemic Risk in the Financial Sector: An Analysis of the Subprime-Mortgage Financial Crisis. Max Planck
Institute for Research on Collective Goods, 2008/43.
Münchau, W. (2009): Die Zeitbombe tickt. Financial Times Deutschland, 18 March 2009, p. 24.
European Council (2009): Proposal for a regulation of the European parliament and the Council establishing a European
Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA) – presidency compromise. Interinstitutional File: 2009/0144 (COD).
Stichele, M.V. (2009): An Oversight of Selected Financial Reforms on the EU Agenda. Centre for Research on Multinational
Corporations. 22 September 2009 (updated version).
Imprint
Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung
International Policy Analysis
Hiroshimastraße 28 | 10785 Berlin | Germany
Responsible:
Dr. Gero Maaß, Head, International Policy Analysis
Tel.: ++49-30-269-35-7745 | Fax: ++49-30-269-35-9248
www.fes.de/ipa
To order publications:
info.ipa@fes.de
The views expressed in this publication are not necessarily
those of the Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung or of the organization for
which the author works.
This publication is printed on paper from sustainable forestry.
About the authors
Prof. Dr. Sebastian Dullien teaches at the Hochschule für
Technik und Wirtschaft / University of Applied Sciences in Berlin.
Prof. Dr. Hansjörg Herr teaches at the Hochschule für
Wirtschaft und Recht in Berlin / Berlin School of Economics and
Law.
ISBN 978-3-86872-341-0