Vi Digital Library - Text Preview
Making Climate Change and Trade Mutually Supportive
Policy brief by Messerlin, Patrick/ ARTNeT, 2010
ARTNeT Policy Brief No. 26 1
ARTNeT POLICY BRIEF
Patrick Messerlin* Brief No. 26, July 2010
Making climate change and trade mutually supportive
* Patrick Messerlin is a Director, Groupe d’Economie Mondiale at Sciences Po. This brief is based on Messerlin. P. (2010). The technical support
provided by ESCAP and the International Development Research Centre, Canada, during the preparation of this brief is gratefully acknowledged.
The views presented are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the United Nations, the author’s employer or other ARTNeT
members and partners.
Asia-Pacific Research and Training Network on Trade • www.artnetontrade.org • Tel: +66 2 288 2067 • Email: artnetontrade@un.org
Introduction
A few years ago, the relations between the climate and
trade communities were marked by mutual ignorance at
best, and more often by deep hostility. The climate
community did not want to be hindered by trade
constraints. The trade community was so afraid of the
damage that climate policies could do to the
multilateral trade regime that it was adamantly opposed
to any consideration of such concerns. Mutual
destruction looked inevitable.
Now things are changing. The trade community is
realizing that climate change concerns will be high on
the political agenda for a long time to come. The
climate community is realizing that climate policies will
face fierce opposition from four-fifths of human kind if it
costs too much in terms of growth and of trade, its main
channel.
However, many fears and doubts still abound. The trade
community remains obsessed by the host of putative
conflicts raised by creative trade lawyers, forgetting that
other domains of international trade law are full of
conflicts that have never materialized. The climate
community has not yet fully realized how easy a prey it
is for protectionist interests, at great cost to climate
change goals. For example, the European Commission
(2009) has formulated a list of industries with “significant
risk of carbon leakage” that includes sectors such as
manufacturing of wines, clocks, bicycles and underwear.
These quite surprising outcomes are easy to explain; one
of the criteria used by the European Commission for
drawing up the list is the importance of trade for the
sectors examined. This criterion, driving the selection of
80 per cent of the sectors in the list, has nothing to do
with climate change, but it is honey for protectionist-
minded sectors.
1. Climate and trade communities: So many things
in common
The main ingredient that is still lacking in the climate and
trade debate is full recognition of the many things that
the climate and trade communities have in common.
First, they share a common problem – each has to deal
with a global “public good”. Climate change is a public
good; countries unwilling to contribute to climate
change goals undermine the results of those making
efforts. Freer trade is a public good; its benefits are
bigger and faster to emerge if all the countries move
together.
Second, the two communities have common foes as
illustrated by the above mentioned European Com-
mission list – the firms willing to slow down climate policies
by using protectionism and those willing to slow down
trade liberalization by using climate change excuses.
Third, they have emerging common friends – those firms
willing to grasp the opportunities of delivering goods that
are both cleaner (good for the climate) and cheaper
(good for trade) as well as countries such as Germany or
China are building up comparative advantages in
environmentally-friendly goods.
Last but not least, the world climate regime has to
develop in a multilateral framework, just as the trade
regime did. There is one Earth, but the Copenhagen
Conference has made it clear that no country is ready
to surrender its sovereign rights. The world carbon price
or tax is an objective that should be aimed for, but it will
emerge in a future as distant as worldwide free trade.
The existence of so many fundamental similarities
strongly suggests that the multilateral climate regime
should not be so different from the multilateral trade
regime. In the following paragraphs, it is argued that the
climate community would greatly benefit from adopting
the two key principles of the multilateral trade regime. It
is also argued that benefits go both ways; the climate
community could design some instruments that could be
repatriated in the multilateral trade regime to its upmost
benefit. Mutual support emerges as highly desirable.
2. From the trade community to the climate
community
The climate community should borrow the multilateral
trade regime’s two key principles – “national treatment”
for disciplining carbon border taxes and “most-favoured
nation” for disciplining carbon tariffs.
2 ARTNeT Policy Brief No. 26
ARTNeT POLICY BRIEF
(a) National treatment
The climate community worries about carbon leakage.
Arguably, carbon border taxes (CBTs) are the best
instrument to fight carbon leakage; why would firms
located in a country shift their dirty production to foreign
countries if, once re-imported, their products would pay
the country’s domestic carbon taxes? If CBTs reassure
the climate community, they make the trade community
nervous. The trade community should be reminded that
such a system has been routinely used with great
success by trading partners enforcing very different rates
of value added tax (VAT) during the past four decades.
Thus, there is nothing wrong with CBTs if – this “if” is
crucial – they are properly enforced, as in the VAT case.
This condition requires the principle of national
treatment, which means that a country should impose
the same domestic tax on imported goods and on
similar products produced domestically. Specifically, it
requires the country exporting goods to eliminate its
domestic carbon taxes (if any) on exported products,
while the importing country imposes its own domestic
carbon taxes (if any) on imported products. Evidence
from the European cap-and-trade regime suggests that
carbon taxes in the dirtiest sectors would be equivalent
to VAT rates of 3 per cent to 6 per cent – not insignificant
numbers, but not large ones either.
In this context, it is interesting to estimate the potential
impact of carbon border taxes. The table suggests three
main results. First, clearly, mutual destruction is a
possibility. Trade-based border taxes on imports result in
massive deterioration of the situation – remarkably – of
almost all the countries, to the point of putting at risk
world growth; hence the willingness and/or capacity to
pursue climate change policies. Second, while the
impact of specific-based border taxes may be less
dramatic it hurts most developing countries, ensuring
political international turmoil.
Last but not least, two border tax regimes have a much
lower impact on trade: (a) the two-way border tax
regime; and (b) the ‘no border tax’ regime. The choice
between these two regimes depends largely on whether
or not developed countries want to do practice what
they preach. If one believes what developed countries
preach, they are cutting their carbon emissions for the
sake of human welfare. Their preferred choice should
then be the ‘no border tax’ regime. Developed countries
would accept a small decline of their exports because it
minimizes the decline of the low- and middle-income
developing countries’ exports. The ‘no border tax’
regime thus emerges as the preferable option from
the joint points of view of climate change (the targeted
CO
2
cut is achieved in developed countries) trade and
development; this is mutual support at its best.
(b) Most-favoured nation
Such a principle would ban the imposition of carbon
tariffs on imports from only certain countries, i.e., China,
India or other key emerging economies. It is crucial to
distinguish between carbon tariffs and carbon border
taxes; carbon tariffs do, in fact, discriminate against
some countries, and they are not defined by the level of
domestic carbon taxes. The most-favoured nation
principle should be a pillar of the multilateral climate
regime, because carbon tariffs are totally counter-
productive from a climate perspective for two reasons.
First, they assume that developed countries import most
of their dirty products from developing countries. This is
not the case, because developing countries still export
mostly goods with relatively low carbon intensity, from
clothing to assembled products. Second, carbon tariffs
would generate a “dual” world economy with a slowly
growing trade between clean countries, and a rapidly
growing trade between dirty countries – not precisely
what the climate community would like to promote.
Interestingly, a trade-centred (and selfish) argument
reinforces these two reasons. Assume, for example, that
rich countries impose carbon tariffs on Chinese exports of
dirty products (on the top of CBT). This treatment will
create strong incentives among Chinese firms to
upgrade as quickly as possible those products they want
Estimated impact of alternative border tax regimes on total industrial exports
(Unit: Per cent changes)
Border tax regimes
a
United States EC
Developing
Brazil China India
countriesb
Only on imports (trade-based) -10.1 -23.2 -14.8 1.9 -20.8 -16.0
Only on imports (specific-based) -6.5 -6.6 -3.2 -2.5 -3.4 -3.2
Two-way tax (specific-based) 0.0 0.5 -2.0 -0.6 -1.8 -2.1
No border tax -2.3 -2.1 -0.1 1.0 -0.9 -0.3
Source: Mattoo and others, 2009. Developed countries are assumed to reduce unilaterally their CO
2
emissions by 17 per cent
Note: EC = European Commission.
a Two-way border tax – elimination of the carbon tax imposed by the exporting country combined with the imposition of the carbon tax
imposed by the importing country. Trade-based BT: the specific carbon tax of the importing country is applied on the carbon content of
the exporting country on imports from the developing countries. Specific-based BT: the specific carbon tax of the importing country is
applied on the carbon content of the importing country on imports from the developing countries and specific-based.
b Low- and middle-income developing countries.
ARTNeT Policy Brief No. 26 3
ARTNeT POLICY BRIEF
to export to the rich countries. In other words, carbon
tariffs will accelerate the emergence of Chinese
competitors in the high-end products – exactly as
voluntary export restraints and antidumping measures
accelerated the technological upgrading of Japanese
and Korean products from the 1970s to the 1990s. This is
not exactly what the supporters of carbon tariffs are
hoping for.
3. From the climate to the trade community
What could the climate community teach the trade
community? Of course, this part is more hypothetical
because the climate regime is still a blank page. Clearly,
however, a sound multilateral climate regime could help
the trade community with several crucial aspects.
(a) Better adjustment policies
The multilateral trade regime has failed to put in place
sound instruments for supporting the adjustment efforts
required by changing economic conditions. It relies on
measures such as antidumping or safeguards, which
have been amply proven to be both ineffective (they
do not promote adjustment) and costly to consumers
(and even to the firms triggering such measures). The
same would inevitably happen if the climate community
were to adopt similar instruments for addressing climate
change-related adjustments.
At this stage, the climate community has the opportunity
to design better instruments – be it well-targeted
subsidies, public regulations or self-regulations – for
addressing the adjustment problems to be met by
producers of carbon-intensive products. If successful, the
climate community would have provided a great
service to the trade community, which could then
renovate its own machinery by adopting similar
instruments for trade-related adjustment problems.
(b) Differentiated treatment of developing countries
The climate community has already adopted the notion
of “common but differentiated responsibilities” when
dealing with developing and least developed countries.
This notion echoes the “special and differentiated
treatment” (S&DT) in the multilateral trade regime.
However, S&DT can be best described as a trap for
developing countries; it is not generous when truly
needed, and it is generally designed in such terms that
it generates perverse impacts (if any) on both the
alleged beneficiaries and the developing countries
excluded from its scope.
The main reason for such negatives effects is that the
trade community has been unable to design a sound
mechanism for “graduating” successful developing
countries. The climate community should therefore be
careful not to duplicate such a mistake; instead, if
deemed necessary, it should design sound, predictable
and progressive conditions of the “graduation” of
developing and least developed countries.
(c) Negotiating techniques
A last source of inspiration that the trade community
could draw from climate diplomacy concerns
negotiating techniques. The climate community has
already begun to negotiate on a “plurilateral” basis, that
is, a core of key large countries, with a few more nations
representing well-defined groups of small countries. The
trade community would be well-advised to adopt similar
techniques for concluding the Doha Round.
4. Challenges ahead
Generally speaking, the climate community should feel
at ease within the broad World Trade Organization
principles. If that community wants to have its own
multilateral treaty, it should make sure the treaty is built
on the same basic principles. Meanwhile, the trade
community should grasp the opportunities to benefit
from the improved disciplines that the climate
community could design, in order to address the
systemic current failures of the multilateral trade regime.
That said, although immensely beneficial, mutual support
raises serious challenges because climate change
policies raise huge difficulties in terms of implementation.
The following four issues require particular care.
(a) Defining “similarity” or “likeness”
National treatment means that countries rely on
domestic information – the one they know best. This is a
highly desirable feature. However, it falls short of
providing a workable definition of “similarity” between
(or “likeness” of) foreign and domestic products, and
production processes. Unfortunately, to say the least, the
multilateral trade regime does not provide any firm
guidance on this issue.
As a result, the climate community has a key role to play
in shaping such a definition. It should be very careful not
to be captured by definitions of “similar” that would
favour vested interests to the detriment of climate
change goals. This implies that similarity should be based
on scientific evidence in two ways. First, such evidence
should be the only criterion for defining carbon intensive
sectors. This is a key step for limiting risks of protectionism.
However, it is also a crucial step for the climate
community because it helps to simplify the otherwise
mind-boggling complexity of climate policies, and to
focus on the sectors that are the true source of
problems. Second, scientific evidence should be used to
build “clusters” of production processes considered to
have similar carbon-intensity and thus subject to the
same carbon tax rate.
(b) Taking into account production and process
methods
These two steps are critical for addressing, in a
pragmatic way, the problem of production and process
methods (PPMs). The logic of climate change problems
4 ARTNeT Policy Brief No. 26
ARTNeT POLICY BRIEF
What is ARTNeT? The Asia-Pacific Research and Training Network on Trade (ARTNeT) is an open
regional network of research and academic instiutions specializing in international trade policy
and facilitation issues. Network members currently include over 25 leading national trade
research and academic institutions from as many developing countries from East, South,
and Southeast Asia and the Pacific. IDRC, UNCTAD, UNDP, ESCAP and the WTO, as core
network partners, provide substantive and/or financial support to the network. The Trade
and Investment Division of ESCAP, the regional branch of the United Nations for Asia and
the Pacific, provides the Secretariat of the network and a direct regional link to trade policymakers and other
international organizations.
ARTNeT aims at increasing the amount of policy-oriented trade research in the region by harnessing the
research capacity already available and developing additional capacity through regional team research
projects, enhanced research dissemination mechanisms, increased interactions between trade policymakers
and researchers, and specific capacity-building activities catering to researchers and research institutions from
least developed countries. A key feature of the network’s operation is that its research programme is discussed
and approved on an annual basis during a consultative meeting of policymakers, research institutions and other
stakeholders. For more information, please contact the ARTNeT Secretariat or visit www.artnetontrade.org.
makes it inevitable that PPMs as well as products per se
must be taken into consideration. Two “like” goods
produced by a dirty and a clean production process are
not similar from a climate perspective. This feature makes
the trade community nervous. However, that community
should also recognize that it implicitly takes into account
production processes when it allows the imposition of
different antidumping duties of “like-products” produced
by different firms. The risk is thus not a matter of
principles, but of sound implementation.
If these two steps are not followed, it creates the risk of
denying the notion of likeness. This would hurt the trade
regime. In addition, it would also harm the climate
regime because it would require the impossible task of
managing an enormous number of “products times
processes” that are subject to a host of different carbon
taxes. Developing these two steps based on scientific
evidence is thus a common interest of the climate and
trade communities. Doing so in a multilateral framework
would make the similarity definitions even more
transparent and unbiased.
(c) How to define carbon border taxes?
The way that carbon border taxes will be defined is
crucial for developing countries. Ensuring a level playing
field is not a simple matter in the case of a public good
because it faces two constraints: (a) from an economic
perspective, past emissions have to be taken into
account as well as present and future emissions; and
(b) from a political perspective, the level of taxation
should not harm growth too strongly if worldwide support
is sought. Of the three possible ways of defining carbon
border taxes, the burden on developing countries
could range from one to two or even three taxes,
depending on the definition chosen. Offering the best
outcome from a joint climate, development and trade
perspective requires the definition of border taxes in ad
valorem terms.
(d) Facing the unexpected
This point is based on the implicit assumption of perfect
forecasts in climate change matters. This assumption is
not met at the regional or local level. For example,
available forecasts on more frequent and severe
droughts in certain regions during the coming 20 to
50 years diverge widely, depending on the model
used. An efficient way to address the problems of
increased scarcity of water, and of its unequal
distribution in the world is more trade between water-rich
and/or water-efficient countries and the other countries
– meaning the opening of their agricultural sectors
(which use 70 per cent to 80 per cent of water
resources) by the developed countries. In short, freer
trade emerges as the cheapest source of insurance
against unexpected shocks in climate change.
To conclude, rather than being afraid of each other, the
climate and trade communities should realize how much
they will lose if they do not cooperate, and how much
they will gain if they support each other.
References
European Commission (2009). “Draft Commission Decision
on determining, pursuant to Directive 2003/87/EC of the
European Parliament and of the Council, a list of sectors
and subsectors which are deemed to be exposed to a
significant risk of carbon leakage”. Available at http://
ec.europa.eu/environment/climat/emission/pdf/
draft_dec_carbon_leakage_list16sep.pdf
Mattoo, A., A. Subramanian, D. van der Mensbrugghe and
J. He. (2009). “Reconciling climate change and trade
policy”, Working Paper No. 09-15. Peterson Institute for
International Economics, Washington, D.C.
Messerlin, P. (2010). “Climate change and trade: From mutual
destruction to mutual support”, Groupe d’Economie
Mondiale Working Paper, April 2010. Sciences Po, Paris.
Available at http://gem.sciences-po.fr.